By Arjun Raina
Unemployment (or joblessness), as defined by the International Labour Organization, occurs when people are without jobs and they have actively sought work within the past four weeks. The unemployment rate is a measure of the prevalence of unemployment and it is calculated as a percentage by dividing the number of unemployed individuals by all individuals currently in the labor force. In a 2011 news story, BusinessWeek reported, "More than 200 million people globally are out of work, a record high, as almost two-thirds of advanced economies and half of developing countries are experiencing a slowdown in employment growth," the group said.
Unemployment (or joblessness), as defined by the International Labour Organization, occurs when people are without jobs and they have actively sought work within the past four weeks. The unemployment rate is a measure of the prevalence of unemployment and it is calculated as a percentage by dividing the number of unemployed individuals by all individuals currently in the labor force. In a 2011 news story, BusinessWeek reported, "More than 200 million people globally are out of work, a record high, as almost two-thirds of advanced economies and half of developing countries are experiencing a slowdown in employment growth," the group said.
History
There are limited historical records on unemployment
because it has not always been acknowledged or measured systematically.
Industrialization involves economies of scale that often prevent individuals
from having the capital to create their own jobs to be self-employed. An
individual who cannot either join an enterprise or create a job is unemployed.
As individual farmers, ranchers, spinners, doctors and merchants are organized
into large enterprises; those who cannot join or compete become unemployed.
Recognition of unemployment occurred slowly as
economies across the world industrialized and bureaucratized. The recognition
of the concept of "unemployment" is best exemplified through the well
documented historical records in England. For example, in 16th century England
no distinction was made between vagrants and the jobless; both were simply
categorized as "sturdy beggars", to be punished and moved on.
The closing of the monasteries in the 1530s increased
poverty, as the church had helped the poor. In addition, there was a
significant rise in enclosure during the Tudor period. Also the population was
rising. Those unable to find work had a stark choice: starve or break the law.
In 1535, a bill was drawn up calling for the creation of a system of public
works to deal with the problem of unemployment, to be funded by a tax on income
and capital. A law passed a year later allowed vagabonds to be whipped and
hanged.
In 1547, a bill was passed that subjected vagrants to
some of the more extreme provisions of the criminal law, namely two years
servitude and branding with a "V" as the penalty for the first
offense and death for the second. During the reign of Henry VIII, as many as
72,000 people are estimated to have been executed. In the 1576 Act each town
was required to provide work for the unemployed.
The Elizabethan Poor Law of 1601, one of the world's
first government-sponsored welfare programs, made a clear distinction between
those who were unable to work and those able-bodied people who refused
employment. Under the Poor Law systems of England and Wales, Scotland and
Ireland a workhouse was a place where people who were unable to support
themselves, could go to live and work.
Definitions,
types and theories
Economists distinguish between various overlapping
types of and theories of unemployment, including cyclical or Keynesian
unemployment, frictional unemployment, structural unemployment and classical
unemployment. Some additional types of unemployment that are occasionally
mentioned are seasonal unemployment, hardcore unemployment, and hidden
unemployment.
Though there have been several definitions of
voluntary and involuntary unemployment in the economics literature, a simple distinction
is often applied. Voluntary unemployment is attributed to the individual's
decisions, whereas involuntary unemployment exists because of the
socio-economic environment (including the market structure, government
intervention, and the level of aggregate demand) in which individuals operate.
In these terms, much or most of frictional unemployment is voluntary, since it
reflects individual search behavior. Voluntary unemployment includes workers
who reject low wage jobs whereas involuntary unemployment includes workers
fired due to an economic crisis, industrial decline, company bankruptcy, or
organizational restructuring.
Classical
unemployment
Classical or real-wage unemployment occurs when real
wages for a job are set above the market-clearing level, causing the number of
job-seekers to exceed the number of vacancies.
Most economists have argued that unemployment
increases the more the government intervenes into the economy to try to improve
the conditions of those without jobs. For example, minimum wage laws raise the
cost of laborers with few skills to above the market equilibrium, resulting in
people who wish to work at the going rate but cannot as wage enforced is
greater than their value as workers becoming unemployed. Laws restricting layoffs
made businesses less likely to hire in the first place, as hiring becomes more
risky, leaving many young people unemployed and unable to find work.
However, this argument is criticized for ignoring
numerous external factors and overly simplifying the relationship between wage
rates and unemployment — in other words, that other factors may also affect unemployment.
Some, such as Murray Rothbard,
suggest that even social taboos can prevent wages from falling to the market
clearing level. It is noted that there can be unemployment when job market is
in equilibrium. For example, the salary of appliance repairman in a city is
$3,000. At this salary, the appliance stores of city want to hire 100
repairmen. But there are 300 repairmen looking for jobs within the city. So
there are 200 repairmen looking for jobs are unemployed. At this time, job
market is not in equilibrium. But six months later, the salary of appliance
repairman in this city drop to $1,000. At this salary, the appliance stores of
city want to hire 200 repairmen. There are 200 repairman want to accept jobs.
For the rest 100 repairmen, they no longer want to work for this kind of job
because the salary is too low. By this time, job market reaches equilibrium.
But there are still 100 repairmen unemployed because they no longer want to
work for this kind of job.
Cyclical unemployment
Cyclical
or Keynesian unemployment, also known as deficient-demand unemployment, occurs
when there is not enough aggregate demand in the economy to provide jobs for
everyone who wants to work. Demand for most goods and services falls, less
production is needed and consequently fewer workers are needed, wages are
sticky and do not fall to meet the equilibrium level, and mass unemployment
results. Its name is derived from the frequent shifts in the business cycle
although unemployment can also be persistent as occurred during the Great
Depression of the 1930s. With cyclical unemployment, the number of unemployed
workers exceeds the number of job vacancies, so that even if full employments
were attained and all open jobs were filled, some workers would still remain
unemployed. Some associate cyclical unemployment with frictional unemployment
because the factors that cause the friction are partially caused by cyclical
variables. For example, a surprise decrease in the money supply may shock
rational economic factors and suddenly inhibit aggregate demand.
Classical
economists reject the conception of cyclical unemployment and alternatively
suggest that the invisible hand of free markets will respond quickly to
unemployment and underutilization of resources by a fall in wages followed by a
rise in employment. Similarly, Hayek and others from the Austrian school of
economics argue that if governments intervene through monetary policy to lower
interest rates this will exacerbate unemployment by preventing the market from
responding effectively.
Keynesian
economists on the other hand see the lack of demand for jobs as potentially
resolvable by government intervention. One suggested interventions involves
deficit spending to boost employment and demand. Another intervention involves
an expansionary monetary policy that increases the demand of money which should
reduce interest rates which should lead to an increase in non-governmental
spending.
The IS-LM Model is used to analyse the effect of
demand shocks on the economy.
Involuntary unemployment
In
The General Theory, Keynes argued that neo-classical economic theory did not
apply during recessions because of excessive savings and weak private
investment in an economy. In consequence, people could be thrown out of work
involuntarily and not be able to find acceptable new employment.
This
conflict between the neoclassical and Keynesian theories has had strong
influence on government policy. The tendency for government is to curtail and
eliminate unemployment through increases in benefits and government jobs, and
to encourage the job-seeker to both consider new careers and relocation to
another city.
Involuntary
unemployment does not exist in agrarian societies nor is it formally recognized
to exist in underdeveloped but urban societies, such as the mega-cities of
Africa and of India/Pakistan. In such societies, a suddenly unemployed person
must meet their survival needs either by getting a new job at any price,
becoming an entrepreneur, or joining the underground economy of the hustler.
Structural unemployment
"Driver
looking for work" Unemployed German laborer in 1949
Structural
unemployment occurs when a labour market is unable to provide jobs for everyone
who wants one because there is a mismatch between the skills of the unemployed
workers and the skills needed for the available jobs. Structural unemployment
is hard to separate empirically from frictional unemployment, except to say
that it lasts longer. As with frictional unemployment, simple demand-side
stimulus will not work to easily abolish this type of unemployment.
Structural
unemployment may also be encouraged to rise by persistent cyclical
unemployment: if an economy suffers from long-lasting low aggregate demand, it
means that many of the unemployed become disheartened, while their skills
(including job-searching skills) become "rusty" and obsolete.
Problems with debt may lead to homelessness and a fall into the vicious circle
of poverty. This means that they may not fit the job vacancies that are created
when the economy recovers. Some economists see this scenario as occurring under
British Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher during the 1970s and 1980s. The
implication is that sustained high demand may lower structural unemployment.
This theory of persistence in structural unemployment has been referred to as
an example of path dependence or "hysteresis".
Okun's Law interprets unemployment as a function
of growth in GDP
Frictional unemployment
Frictional
unemployment is the time period between jobs when a worker is searching for, or
transitioning from one job to another. It is sometimes called search
unemployment and can be voluntary based on the circumstances of the unemployed
individual. Frictional unemployment is always present in an economy, so the
level of involuntary unemployment is properly the unemployment rate minus the
rate of frictional unemployment, which means that increases or decreases in
unemployment are normally under-represented in the simple statistics.
Frictional
unemployment exists because both jobs and workers are heterogeneous, and a
mismatch can result between the characteristics of supply and demand. Such a
mismatch can be related to skills, payment, work-time, location, seasonal
industries, attitude, taste, and a multitude of other factors. New entrants
(such as graduating students) and re-entrants (such as former homemakers) can
also suffer a spell of frictional unemployment. Workers as well as employers
accept a certain level of imperfection, risk or compromise, but usually not
right away; they will invest some time and effort to find a better match. This
is in fact beneficial to the economy since it results in a better allocation of
resources. However, if the search takes too long and mismatches are too
frequent, the economy suffers, since some work will not get done. Therefore,
governments will seek ways to reduce unnecessary frictional unemployment
through multiple means including providing education, advice, training, and
assistance such as daycare centers.
The
frictions in the labour market are sometimes illustrated graphically with a
Beveridge curve, a downward-sloping, convex curve that shows a correlation
between the unemployment rate on one axis and the vacancy rate on the other.
Changes in the supply of or demand for labour cause movements along this curve.
An increase (decrease) in labour market frictions will shift the curve outwards
(inwards).
Hidden unemployment
Hidden,
or covered, unemployment is the unemployment of potential workers that is not
reflected in official unemployment statistics, due to the way the statistics
are collected. In many countries only those who have no work but are actively
looking for work (and/or qualifying for social security benefits) are counted
as unemployed. Those who have given up looking for work (and sometimes those
who are on Government "retraining" programs) are not officially
counted among the unemployed, even though they are not employed. The same
applies to those who have taken early retirement to avoid being laid off, but
would prefer to be working. The statistic also does not count the
"underemployed" — those working fewer hours than they would prefer or
in a job that doesn't make good use of their capabilities. In addition, those
who are of working age but are currently in full-time education are usually not
considered unemployed in government statistics. Official statistics often
underestimate unemployment rates because of hidden unemployment.
Long-term unemployment
This
is normally defined, for instance in European Union statistics, as unemployment
lasting for longer than one year. It is an important indicator of social
exclusion. The United States Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) reports this as
27 weeks or longer.
Effects
Costs
Individual
Unemployed
individuals are unable to earn money to meet financial obligations. Failure to
pay mortgage payments or to pay rent may lead to homelessness through
foreclosure or eviction. Across the United States the growing ranks of people
made homeless in the foreclosure crisis are generating tent cities.
Unemployment increases susceptibility to malnutrition, illness, mental stress,
and loss of self-esteem, leading to depression. According to a study published
in Social Indicator Research, even those who tend to be optimistic find it
difficult to look on the bright side of things when unemployed. Using
interviews and data from German participants aged 16 to 94 – including
individuals coping with the stresses of real life and not just a volunteering
student population – the researchers determined that even optimists struggled
with being unemployed.
Dr.
M. Brenner conducted a study in 1979 on the "Influence of the Social
Environment on Psychology." Brenner found that for every 10% increase in
the number of unemployed there is an increase of 1.2% in total mortality, a
1.7% increase in cardiovascular disease, 1.3% more cirrhosis cases, 1.7% more
suicides, 4.0% more arrests, and 0.8% more assaults reported to the police. A
more recent study by Christopher Ruhm on the effect of recessions on health
found that several measures of health actually improve during recessions. As
for the impact of an economic downturn on crime, during the Great Depression
the crime rate did not decrease. The unemployed in the U.S. often use welfare
programs such as Food Stamps or accumulating debt because unemployment
insurance in the U.S. generally does not replace a majority of the income one
received on the job (and one cannot receive such aid indefinitely). Unemployed men outside a soup kitchen
in Chicago, 1931
Social
An
economy with high unemployment is not using all of the resources, specifically
labour, available to it. Since it is operating below its production possibility
frontier, it could have higher output if all the workforce were usefully
employed. However, there is a trade-off between economic efficiency and
unemployment: if the frictionally unemployed accepted the first job they were
offered, they would be likely to be operating at below their skill level,
reducing the economy's efficiency.
During
a long period of unemployment, workers can lose their skills, causing a loss of
human capital. Being unemployed can also reduce the life expectancy of workers
by about 7 years.
High
unemployment can encourage xenophobia and protectionism as workers fear that
foreigners are stealing their jobs. Efforts to preserve existing jobs of
domestic and native workers include legal barriers against
"outsiders" who want jobs, obstacles to immigration, and/or tariffs
and similar trade barriers against foreign competitors.
High
unemployment can also cause social problems such as crime; if people have less
disposable income than before, it is very likely that crime levels within the
economy will increase.
Demonstration
against unemployment in Kerala, India
Socio-political
High
levels of unemployment can be causes of civil unrest, in some cases leading to
revolution, and particularly totalitarianism. The fall of the Weimar Republic
in 1933 and Adolf Hitler's rise to power, which culminated in World War II and
the deaths of tens of millions and the destruction of much of the physical
capital of Europe, is attributed to the poor economic conditions in Germany at
the time, notably a high unemployment rate of above 20%; see Great Depression
in Central Europe for details.
Note
that the hyperinflation in the Weimar Republic is not directly blamed for the
Nazi rise – the Inflation in the Weimar Republic occurred primarily in the
period 1921–23, which was contemporary with Hitler's Beer Hall Putsch of 1923,
and is blamed for damaging the credibility of democratic institutions, but the
Nazis did not assume government until 1933, ten years after the hyperinflation
but in the midst of high unemployment.
Rising
unemployment has traditionally been regarded by the public and media in any
country as a key guarantor of electoral defeat for any government which
oversees it. This was very much the consensus in the United Kingdom until 1983,
when Margaret Thatcher's Conservative government won a landslide in the general
election, despite overseeing a rise in unemployment from 1,500,000 to 3,200,000
since its election four years earlier.
Benefits
The
primary benefit of unemployment is that people are available for hire, without
being headhunted away from their existing employers. This permits new and old
businesses to take on staff.
Unemployment
is argued[citation needed] to be "beneficial" to the people who are
not unemployed in the sense that it averts inflation, which itself has damaging
effects, by providing (in Marxian terms) a reserve army of labour, that keeps
wages in check. However the direct connection between full local employment and
local inflation has been disputed by some due to the recent increase in international
trade that supplies low-priced goods even while local employment rates rise to
full employment.
Full
employment cannot be achieved because workers would shirk if they were not
threatened with the possibility of unemployment. The curve for the no-shirking
condition (labelled NSC) goes to infinity at full employment as a result. The
inflation-fighting benefit to the entire economy arising from a presumed
optimum level of unemployment has been studied extensively. The
Shapiro-Stiglitz model suggests that wages are not bid down sufficiently to
ever reach 0% unemployment. This occurs because employers know that when wages
decrease, workers will shirk and expend less effort. Employers avoid shirking
by preventing wages from decreasing so low that workers give up and become
unproductive. These higher wages perpetuate unemployment while the threat of
unemployment reduces shirking.
Decline in work hours
As a
result of productivity the work week declined considerably over the 19th
century. By the 1920s in the U.S. the average work week was 49 hours, but the
work week was reduced to 40 hours (after which overtime premium was applied) as
part of the National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933. At the time of the Great
Depression of the 1930s it was understood that with the enormous productivity
gains due to electrification, mass production and agricultural mechanization,
there was no need for a large number of previously employed workers.
Controlling or reducing unemployment
Societies
try a number of different measures to get as many people as possible into work,
and various societies have experienced close to full employment for extended
periods, particularly during the Post-World War II economic expansion. The
United Kingdom in the 1950s and 60s averaged 1.6% unemployment, while in
Australia the 1945 White Paper on Full Employment in Australia established a
government policy of full employment, which policy lasted until the 1970s when
the government ran out of money.
However,
mainstream economic discussions of full employment since the 1970s suggest that
attempts to reduce the level of unemployment below the natural rate of
unemployment will fail, resulting only in less output and more inflation.
Demand side solutions
Many
countries aid the unemployed through social welfare programs. These
unemployment benefits include unemployment insurance, unemployment
compensation, welfare and subsidies to aid in retraining. The main goal of
these programs is to alleviate short-term hardships and, more importantly, to
allow workers more time to search for a job.
A
direct demand-side solution to unemployment is government-funded employment of
the able-bodied poor. This was notably implemented in Britain from the 17th
century until 1948 in the institution of the workhouse, which provided jobs for
the unemployed with harsh conditions and poor wages to dissuade their use. A
modern alternative is a job guarantee, where the government guarantees work at
a living wage. Temporary measures can include public works programs such as the
Works Progress Administration. Government-funded employment is not widely
advocated as a solution to unemployment, except in times of crisis; this is
attributed to the public sector jobs' existence depending directly on the tax
receipts from private sector employment.
In
the U.S. the unemployment insurance allowance one receives is based solely on
previous income (not time worked, family size, etc.) and usually compensates
for one-third of one's previous income. To qualify, one must reside in their
respective state for at least a year and, of course, work. The system was
established by the Social Security Act of 1935. Although 90% of citizens are
covered by unemployment insurance, less than 40% apply for and receive
benefits. However, the number applying for and receiving benefits increases
during recessions. In cases of highly seasonal industries the system provides
income to workers during the off seasons, thus encouraging them to stay
attached to the industry.
According
to classical economic theory, markets reach equilibrium where supply equals
demand; everyone who wants to sell at the market price can. Those who do not
want to sell at this price do not; in the labour market this is classical
unemployment. Increases in the demand for labour will move the economy along
the demand curve, increasing wages and employment. The demand for labour in an
economy is derived from the demand for goods and services. As such, if the
demand for goods and services in the economy increases, the demand for labour
will increase, increasing employment and wages.
Monetary
policy and fiscal policy can both be used to increase short-term growth in the
economy, increasing the demand for labour and decreasing unemployment.
Government unemployment office with job listings,
Berlin, Germany.
However,
the labour market is not 100% efficient: It does not clear, though it may be
more efficient than bureaucracy. Some argue that minimum wages and union
activity keep wages from falling, which means too many people want to sell
their labour at the going price but cannot. This assumes perfect competition
exists in the labour market, specifically that no single entity is large enough
to affect wage levels. Advocates of supply-side policies believe those policies
can solve this by making the labour market more flexible. These include
removing the minimum wage and reducing the power of unions. Supply-siders argue
the reforms increase long-term growth. This increased supply of goods and
services requires more workers, increasing employment. It is argued that
supply-side policies, which include cutting taxes on businesses and reducing
regulation, create jobs and reduce unemployment. Other supply-side policies
include education to make workers more attractive to employers.
Nice one...
ReplyDeletethnx harsh
ReplyDelete