By Deepak Kumar
Positive Externalities of
Production
RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN AC AND MC
Average cost
In
economics, average cost or unit cost is equal to total cost divided
by the number of goods produced (the output quantity, Q). It is also equal to
the sum of average variable costs (total variable costs divided by Q) plus
average fixed costs (total fixed costs divided by Q). Average costs may be
dependent on the time period considered (increasing production may be expensive
or impossible in the short term, for example). Average costs affect the supply
curve and are a fundamental component of supply and demand.

Short-run
average cost
Short-run
average cost will vary in relation to the quantity produced unless fixed costs
are zero and variable costs constant. A cost curve can be plotted, with cost on
the y-axis and quantity on the x-axis. Marginal costs are often shown on these
graphs, with marginal cost representing the cost of the last unit produced at
each point; marginal costs are the first derivative of total or variable costs.
A
typical average cost curve will have a U-shape, because fixed costs are all
incurred before any production takes place and marginal costs are typically increasing,
because of diminishing marginal productivity. In this "typical" case,
for low levels of production marginal costs are below average costs, so average
costs are decreasing as quantity increases. An increasing marginal cost curve
will intersect a U-shaped average cost curve at its minimum, after which point
the average cost curve begins to slope upward. For further increases in
production beyond this minimum, marginal cost is above average costs, so
average costs are increasing as quantity increases. An example of this typical
case would be a factory designed to produce a specific quantity of widgets per
period: below a certain production level, average cost is higher due to
under-utilised equipment, while above that level, production bottlenecks increase
the average cost.
Long-run average cost
The
long run is a time frame in which the firm can vary the quantities used of all
inputs, even physical capital. A long-run average cost curve can be upward
sloping, downward sloping, or downward sloping at relatively low levels of
output and upward sloping at relatively high levels of output, with an
in-between level of output at which the slope of long-run average cost is zero.
The typical long-run average cost curve is U-shaped, by definition reflecting
increasing returns to scale where negatively-sloped and decreasing returns to
scale where positively sloped
Marginal cost
In economics
and finance, marginal cost is the change in total cost that arises when
the quantity produced changes by one unit. That is, it is the cost of producing
one more unit of a good. If the good being produced is infinitely divisible, so
the size of a marginal cost will change with volume, as a non-linear and
non-proportional cost function includes the following:
- variable terms dependent to volume,
- constant terms independent to volume and occurring with the respective lot size,
- jump fix cost increase or decrease dependent to steps of volume increase.
If the
cost function is differentiable joining, the marginal cost is the cost of the next
unit produced referring to the basic volume.

If the
cost function is not differentiable, the marginal cost can be expressed as
follows.

A typical marginal cost curve with marginal revenue overlaid
Relationship to marginal cost
When
average cost is declining as output increases, marginal cost is less than
average cost. When average cost is rising, marginal cost is greater than
average cost. When average cost is neither rising nor falling (at a minimum or
maximum), marginal cost equals average cost.
Other special cases for average
cost and marginal cost appear frequently:
- Constant marginal cost/high fixed costs: each additional unit of production is produced at constant additional expense per unit. The average cost curve slopes down continuously, approaching marginal cost. An example may be hydroelectric generation, which has no fuel expense, limited maintenance expenses and a high up-front fixed cost (ignoring irregular maintenance costs or useful lifespan). Industries where fixed marginal costs obtain, such as electrical transmission networks, may meet the conditions for a natural monopoly, because once capacity is built, the marginal cost to the incumbent of serving an additional customer is always lower than the average cost for a potential competitor. The high fixed capital costs are a barrier to entry.
- Minimum efficient scale / maximum efficient scale: marginal or average costs may be non-linear, or have discontinuities. Average cost curves may therefore only be shown over a limited scale of production for a given technology. For example, a nuclear plant would be extremely inefficient (very high average cost) for production in small quantities; similarly, its maximum output for any given time period may essentially be fixed, and production above that level may be technically impossible, dangerous or extremely costly. The long run elasticity of supply will be higher, as new plants could be built and brought on-line.
- Zero fixed costs (long-run analysis) / constant marginal cost: since there are no economies of scale, average cost will be equal to the constant marginal cost.
Negative externalities of
production
Negative Externalities of Production
Much
of the time, private and social costs do not diverge from one another, but at
times social costs may be either greater or less than private costs. When
marginal social costs of production are greater than that of the private cost
function, we see the occurrence of a negative externality of production.
Productive processes that result in pollution are a textbook example of
production that creates negative externalities.
Such
externalities are a result of firms externalising their costs onto a third
party in order to reduce their own total cost. As a result of externalising
such costs we see that members of society will be negatively affected by such
behavior of the firm. In this case, we see that an increased cost of production
on society creates a social cost curve that depicts a greater cost than the
private cost curve.
Positive externalities of production
When
marginal social costs of production are less than that of the private cost
function, we see the occurrence of a positive externality of production.
Production of public goods are a textbook example of production that create
positive externalities. An example of such a public good, which creates a
divergence in social and private costs, includes the production of education.
It is often seen that education is a positive for any whole society, as well as
a positive for those directly involved in the market.
Examining
the relevant diagram we see that such production creates a social cost curve
that is less than that of the private curve. In an equilibrium state we see
that markets creating positive externalities of production will under produce
that good. As a result, the socially optimal production level would be greater
than that observed.
Economies of scale
Economies
of scale is a concept that applies to the long run, a span of time in which all
inputs can be varied by the firm so that there are no fixed inputs or fixed
costs. Production may be subject to economies of scale (or diseconomies of
scale). Economies of scale are said to exist if an additional unit of output
can be produced for less than the average of all previous units— that is, if
long-run marginal cost is below long-run average cost, so the latter is
falling. Conversely, there may be levels of production where marginal cost is
higher than average cost, and average cost is an increasing function of output.
For this generic case, minimum average cost occurs at the point where average
cost and marginal cost are equal (when plotted, the marginal cost curve
intersects the average cost curve from below); this point will not be at
the minimum for marginal cost if fixed costs are greater than zero.
No comments:
Post a Comment